Journal of Economics and Financial Analysis, Vol:2, No:1 (2017) 99-128
A Study on Regime Type and Globalization in Simultaneous Equation Framework
Department of Economics, North-Eastern Hill University, India
Abstract
In this study we build a simultaneous equation model in which the measures of different aspects of globalization (attributable to KOF) and different aspects of democracy (attributable to EIU) are related in seven structural equations. A bi-directional relationship between democracy and globalization is visualized. The model is estimated by the conventional 2-SLS as well as a modified 2-SLS in which Shapley value regression is used at the second stage of 2-SLS. On the basis of our analysis, we document several findings. First, we find that democracy and globalization promote each other and hence there is a bi- directional causality with positive relationships running both ways between democracy and globalization. At a national level, there may be various intermediary conditions that modify the relationship as well as set in motion a complex of positive and/or negative feedbacks to accelerate or retard the pace of globalization and democratization in a country-specific manner. However, when a large number of countries are studied, a clear relationship emerges out. Second, there is a need to estimate the structural coefficients of the model cautiously since the regression equations may be suffering from collinearity among the predictor variables. The Shapley value regression based 2-SLS has performed better than the conventional regression in estimating the structural parameters of the model. Third, the system methods of estimation of the model gives better results than what are obtained by the single equation methods of estimation of structural parameters of the model.
Keywords: Simultaneous equations model; Two-Stage Least Squares; Instrumental Variables; Collinearity; Shapley Value Regression; Democracy Index; Globalization Index.
JEL Classification: C30, C36, C51, C57, C61, C71, F63.
* Professor (Rtd.). E-mail addresses: mishrasknehu@hotmail.com
I am thankful to Prof. David Simon Hall for his critical comments that improved the paper significantly. However, the remaining imperfections are solely attributable to me.
Introduction
The bearing of regime type (that has democracy and authoritarianism at two opposite poles) on globalization are debatable. On the one hand, there are research findings and arguments that suggest a positive influence of democratic attributes in governance on globalization, while, on the other hand, there are empirical studies as well as consorted line of reasoning that favours authoritarian elements in governance to promoting globalization. Reversing the arrow of causality, some scholars have given the logic along with empirical evidences that globalization promotes democracy while some others have reasons to contend that globalization hurts democracy. Since a political regime has more pervasive, direct and explicit effects, the issue of impacts of globalization on democracy has elicited more attention of the scholars.
Economists such as Schumpeter (1950), Lipset (1959), and Hayek (1960) argue that free trade and capital flows, by enhancing the efficiency of resource allocation lead to economic development which fosters demand for democracy. Schwartzman (1998) identifies class conflict as the social mechanism linking world-system processes to national political dynamics. In this framework, domestic political structures become part of the evolving transnational fabric of economic relations. Consequently, globalization promotes democracy at the national level which in turn facilitates further globalization in the interest of the dominant world economic system.
Li and Reuveny (2003) study 127 countries for 26 years (1970-1996) and finds that different constituents of globalization affect democracy in different manner not conformal to each other. In their own words: “Trade openness and portfolio investment inflows negatively affect democracy. The effect of trade openness is constant over time while the negative effect of portfolio investment inflows strengthens. FDI inflows positively affect democracy, but the effect weakens over time. The spread of democratic ideas promotes democracy persistently over time.”
Sobhan (2003) argues that the process of globalization represents involuntary and often extraneous constraints on the government and the people of a country. Countries with weak democratic institutions and undiversified or externally dependent economies fall prey to the globalization forces. Globalization may favourably help the economies that can diversify and where political institutions are strong enough to protect the interests of the citizens of different sections. Rudra (2005) covers 59 developing countries for the time period 1972-97 and finds that globalization does not directly and unconditionally promote democracy. Increasing exposure to international export and financial markets does lead to improvements in democracy only if safety nets are used simultaneously as a strategy for providing stability and building political support.
Eichengreen and Lebang (2006) analyses a long series of historical data (1870-2000) for a large number of countries and finds a bidirectional causality suggesting the existence of positive relationships running both ways between democracy and globalization. For Acemoglu and Robinson (2006a) the relationship between development and political regime is not a direct one. The political regime type shapes and is also shaped by economic conflict between elites and citizens. Political elites are unlikely to block development when there is a high degree of political competition or when they are highly entrenched. Expected political replacement effect has a direct bearing on the involvement of the elite class in a country in facilitating or discouraging globalization. Acemoglu and Robinson (2006b) also observe that key democratizing forces associated with trade openness depend on country’s relative factor endowment.
Milner and Mukherjee (2009) studies 130 developing countries in the period 1975-2002 distributed over different continents. It finds that democracy fosters trade and capital account liberalization, while the effect of economic openness on democracy is positive but weak. Neither trade nor capital account liberalization has any statistically significant effect on democratization. Turyahikayo (2014) examines the impact of globalization on domestic political structures and processes in established, transitional and non-democratic regimes. It reveals that globalization has been used as a tool by the established democracies with strong economies to exploit transitional governments and non- democracies through expanding the range of exploitative investment to bring poorer countries in the ambit of influence. Such an expansion feeds on cheap labour. The destination countries of such investment also work as dumping ground for the industrial waste.
Steiner (2015) studies macro-level dataset on legislative elections in 23 established democracies over the period 1965-2006 to test the hypothesis that higher levels of economic globalization result in lower turnout (for voting). The results of the study emphatically indicate that economic globalization has negative effects on electoral turnout in established democracies on account of reduced party polarization (low dispersion) with limited option with regard to economic policy that also induces citizens to think of contesting parties as having less influence on the economy. In view of this, globalization may have a negative effect on public participation in the political domain.
Nayyar (2015) observes that the relationship between democracy and globalization is dialectical rather than linear or unidirectional. The causation runs in both directions in different spheres whose interaction shapes the outcome. Stein (2016) investigates into the question whether a sovereign state system, democratic governments, and an integrated global marketplace can coexist. It assesses analytic materialist arguments for their incompatibility and the key assumptions on which they rest. It “describes the extant pressures operating to limit each of the three: how sovereignty and democracy work to constrain globalization, how globalization and sovereignty generate a democratic deficit, and how globalization and democracy lead to limitations upon, and even the transcendence of, sovereignty.”
Haffoudhi and Bellakhal (2016) finds that the impact of globalization on democracy is demographic-regime specific. Countries that overlooked Malthusian constraints fostered democracy, whereas countries with late demographic transitions, suffering yet of Malthusian constraints, famines and chronic under- nutrition or failed to invest in human capital and consequently have had inefficient resource allocation, also fail to promote democracy. Kollias and Paleologou (2016) studies the relationship between KOF 1 globalization indices and Polity measures of democracy in 110 countries of different income levels (high, medium and low) for the period 1970-2011 and finds a positive impact of globalization on democracy, but this is not universally true across all income groups since any effect exerted by globalization on democracy may differ depending on a country’s attributes.
This brief review of research suggests that the relationship between globalization and democracy (or the political regime of whatever type) may not be direct. It is mediated by the country-specific institutions, class interests, resource endowments, institutional structure, demographic characteristics, involvement and effectiveness of the national government in proper management of the economy and the polity and so on. Depending on mediating forces globalization and democratization may have mutually reinforcing or mutually conflicting relationship. However, irrespective of the country-specific scenarios, a canonical correlation analysis of the measures of democracy and the measures of globalization of a large number of countries indicates that democracy and globalization are conformal to each other.
The Present Study
The investigation at hand acknowledges bi-directional causality between globalization and democracy (or the political regime that has full democracy at the one end and authoritarianism at the other). It holds that the regime type affects the extent of globalization and also that globalization affects the regime type tending to favour democratization.
To capture the bi-directional causality mentioned above, this study constructs a simultaneous equation model in which five measures (detailed out below) of different aspects of a regime, ranging between the two poles of full democracy and authoritarianism, aim at explaining six indicators of globalization (detailed out below). Additionally, some of the indicators of globalization influence the overall index of democracy. The globalization indicators as well as the overall index of democracy are, thus, the endogenous variables in the model while the indicators of political regime are predetermined (exogenous) variables.
The Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU), a British business within the Economist Group has published the Democracy Index for 2006, 2008 and 2011 and for every year afterwards up to 2016. The index is based on 60 indicators grouped in five different categories or dimensions of regime ranging from democracy to authoritarianism. These categories are: Electoral process and pluralism (EPP), Functioning of government (FOG), Political participation (PPN), Political culture (PCL) and Civil liberties (CVL), each one measured by an index.
The five measures of different aspects of democracy (EPP, FOG, PPN, PCL and CVL) mentioned above pertaining to any particular year may be suitably weighted and aggregated to yield an overall index (DI, or the Index of Democracy with the score value in the range of zero to ten). On the basis of the score value (DI) the political systems of different countries may be classified into Full democracies (score value in 8-10 range), Flawed democracies (score value in 6 to below-8 range), Hybrid regimes (score value in 4 to below-6 range) and authoritarian regimes (score value below 4).
The KOF2 visualizes three aspects of globalization: economic, social and political. The economic aspect of globalization is measured by two indices, the social aspect of globalization is measured by three indices and the political aspect has only one measure. The indices of globalization are, thus, six in number. They are: (1) E1 - actual economic flows such as trans-border trade, direct investment and portfolio investment, (2) E2 - relaxation of restrictions on trans-border trade as well as capital movement by means of taxation, tariff, etc., (3) S1 - trans-border personal contacts such as degree of tourism, telecom traffic, postal interactions, etc., (4) S2 - flow of information, (5) S3 - cultural proximity, and (6) P - the measure of trans-national political set up. All the six (E1 through P), by a scheme of linear combination, are used to arrive at the overall composite index of globalization (say, Γ) as described in Dreher (2006) and Dreher et al. (2008). Mishra (2017) uses Almost Equi-Marginal Contribution (AEMC) principle for making a linear combination of globalization aspect indicators E through P. Unlike the KOF index of globalization (based on linear aggregation through the Principal Component Analysis), the AEMC index of globalization is based on the linear aggregation such that the expected mean marginal contributions (Shapley value shares) of all constituent variables to the synthetic index are as close to each other as possible. The composite index of globalization based on AEMC principle may be denoted by G.
Table 1. Summary for Data Abbrevation and Description
Abbrevation
Description
EPP
Electoral process and pluralism;
FOG
Functioning of government;
PPN
Political participation;
PCL
Political culture;
CVL
Civil liberties;
DI
Index of Democracy with score value range between 0-10;
E1
Actual economic flows such as trans-border trade, direct investment and portfolio investment;
E2
Relaxation of restrictions on trans-border trade as well as capital
movement by means of taxation, tariff, etc.;
S1
Trans-border personal contacts such as degree of tourism, telecom
traffic, postal interactions, etc.;
S2
Flow of information;
S3
Cultural proximity;
P
The measure of trans-national political set up.
A Simultaneous Equation Model of Globalization and Regime Type
Since our study visualizes a bi-directional causal relationship between democracy (political regime type) and globalization, the measures of different aspects (economic, social and political) of globalization are endogenous variables that directly or indirectly influence each other. The overall democracy index at a later date (DI16 for the year 2016) also is one of the endogenous variables influenced by the globalization indices of the earlier date (during 2006-2014). The measures of different aspects of democracy (for the year 2006) are the predetermined (exogenous) variables. Our simultaneous equation model is given in the schematic form as under. We have made a comparative study of two scenarios that we describe in the next section. In the model below, t is denoting pessimistic or optimistic vector pertaining to the two scenarios. All the relationships in the model characterize following linear equations (abbreviations in table 1).
Data on the Measures of Democracy and Globalization
Under our study there are 116 countries distributed over the continents, viz. Africa, the Americas, Asia, Australia, Europe and Oceania. These countries together represent all types of political regime (full democracy to authoritarian) and all levels of globalization (very low, medium and high). The data used by us are presented in the appended tables: Table A1, Table A2 and Table A3.
In table A1 we present five measures for democracy (EPPi06, FOGi06, PPNi06, PCLi06 and CVLi06; i=1 through 116) for the year 2006 as well as the overall measure of democracy for 2016. The measures of democracy for 2006 make our exogenous variables while the overall measure of democracy for 2016 (DIi16 i=1,2,..., 116) is one of our endogenous variables.
As to the measures of different aspects of globalization, we have used the KOF indices3 for the period 2006-2014. However, we have not used a time series data for any country under study for the entire period 2006-2014. From the available time series over the years (for all countries under study), we have formed two scenarios. For any particular 𝑖𝑖𝑡𝑡ℎ country (among 116 countries considered in the study at hand) we have G for 9 years, 2006-2014 that we denote by Gij; j=2006 through 2014 and i=1 through 116.
For every Gij we have the associated sub-indices [E1ij, E2ij, S1ij, S2ij, S3ij and Pij ; j=2006 through 2014 and i=1 through 116]. We have constructed two vectors:
which is associated with
that gives us the set of values associated with the lowest extent of globalization experienced by any country during 2006-2014.
Similarly,
which is associated with
that gives us the set of values associated with the highest extent of globalization experienced by any country during 2006-2014. We may call them pessimistic (associated with G min ) and optimistic (associated with G max ) vectors of globalization. We have these two vectors as our endogenous variables for estimating the model for pessimistic effects of the indicators of the political regime and optimistic effects of the indicators of the political regime.
Estimation of the Model
There are several methods to estimate a simultaneous equation model that may be primarily classified into two groups: (1) single equation methods, and (2) system methods. The single equation methods are easy to apply and free from the undesirable effects of misspecification of other equations in the model, but they are susceptible to the detrimental effects of disturbances correlated across the equations. The system methods are cumbersome and susceptible to the problems of misspecification of equations in the model, but they perform well even if the disturbances across the equations are correlated. Between the single equation and the system methods of estimation, thus, there is a trade-off between deleterious effects of ‘misspecification’ and ‘correlated residuals across the equations’ in the model. Since little is known about correct specification of different equations in our model, we have favoured the single equation method of estimation for ease in computation as well as for avoiding the possible risk in proceeding to the system method of estimation under the circumstances of misspecification. We also do not have reasons to assume the disturbances in the equations to be normally distributed. Under these circumstances we have chosen the Two-Stage Least Squares (2-SLS) method of estimation since it handles instrumental variables in a very natural manner.
3 KOF [Konjunkturforschungsstelle or Economic Research Centre of ETH Zurich]. 2017 Index of globalization. http://globalization.kof.ethz.ch/media/filer_public/2017/04/19/rankings_2017.pdf
The Two-Stage Least Squares for structural Equations
If an econometric model is specified as YA + XB + U = 0 (where Y are current endogenous and X are predetermined variables), the 2-SLS method first obtains the Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) based expected values of Y by the relationship Ŷ= XC (where C is the matrix of reduced form coefficients) and in order to proceed to the second stage substitute the estimated ŷ for observed y in the equation wherever it is a regressor variable (and not the regressand variable). Thus, among the regressor variables ŷ would be used as an instrumental variable (Reiersol, 1945) representing y, while x is its own instrument. This approach renders the use of OLS at the second stage free from the stochastic regressor problem.
Possible Collinearity among Regressors at the 2nd Stage and its Treatment
However, since at the second stage, the 2-SLS uses the estimated values of some endogenous variables together with some predetermined variables as regressors, collinearity among the regressor variables may arise. This is because the estimated values of endogenous variables are the linear functions of the predetermined variables in the model. Collinearity may affect standard errors of the estimated parameters. Signs of the estimated parameters also may be wrong (Smith and Brainard, 1976). In view of this, we have also used the Shapley value regression at the second stage of 2-SLS and compared the results of this choice with the conventional method that uses OLS at the second stage.
The Shapley Value Regression
Shapley value regression significantly ameliorates the deleterious effects of collinearity on the estimated parameters of a regression equation. The concept of Shapley value was introduced in (cooperative collusive) game theory where agents form collusion and cooperate with each other to raise the value of a game in their favour and later divide it among themselves. Distribution of the value of the game according to Shapley decomposition has been shown to have many desirable properties (Roth, 1988, pp.1-10) including linearity, unanimity, marginalism, etc. Following this theory of sharing of the value of a game, the Shapley value regression decomposes the R2 of a conventional regression (which is considered as the value of the collusive cooperative game) such that the mean expected marginal contribution of every predictor variable (agents in collusion to explain the variation in y, the dependent variable) sums up to R2.
The scheme of Shapley value regression is simple. Suppose z is the dependent variable and x1, x2, ... , xk ∈ X are the predictor variables, which may have strong collinearity. Let Yi ⊂ X in which xi ∈ X is not there or xi ∉ Yi. Thus, Yi will have only k-1 variables. We draw r (r=0, 1, 2, ... , k-1) variables from Yi and let this collection of variables so drawn be called Pr such that Pr ⊆ Yi . Also, Yi = Yi∪ ∅. Now, Pr can be drawn in L=kCr ways. Also, let Qr = Pr ∪ xi. Regress (least squares) z on Qr to find R2 . Regress (least squares) z on P to obtain R2 . The difference between the two R-squares is Dr = R2 - R2 , which is the marginal contribution of x to z. This is done for all L combinations for a given r and arithmetic mean of Dr (over the sum of all L values of Dr) is computed. Once it is obtained for each r, its arithmetic mean is computed. Note that Pr is null for r=0, and thus Qr contains a single variable, namely xi. Further, when Pr is null, its R2 is zero. The result is the arithmetic average of the mean (or expected) marginal contributions of xi to z. This is done for all xi; i=1, k to obtain the Shapley value (Si) of xi; i=1, k. In the regression model z=Xb+u, the OLS gives a value of R2. The sum of all Si; i=1,2, ..., k is equal to R2. Thus, OLS R2 has been decomposed. Once all Shapley value shares are known, one may retrieve the coefficients (with original scale and origin) by solving an optimization problem suggested by Lipovetsky (2006) using any appropriate optimization method. A simple algorithm and computer program is available in Mishra (2016).
Empirical Findings
As pointed out earlier, we have used two alternative vectors of globalization measures, the one related to Gmin and the other related to Gmax. Therefore, we have two parallel findings, the one for a pessimistic view and the other for an optimistic view of globalization.
The reduced form coefficients matrices C (based on OLS) are given in table 2 for pessimistic and optimistic views of globalization at Panel A and Panel B respectively. Their standard errors are not presented because the coefficients are used only to obtain the expected values of endogenous variables.
Table 2. Estimated Reduced Form Coefficients Matrix (Transposed C)
Equation Number
Regressand Variable
Reduced Form Coefficients of Predictor Variables
(All Predetermined) Relating to Political Regime
R2
EPP
FOG
PPN
PCL
CVL
CONST
Panel A: Pessimistic Scenario of Globalization
1
E1
-0.09669
0.24146
0.24643
0.18092
0.08821
23.34796
0.3753
2
E2
0.09687
0.28829
-0.00578
0.20171
0.00678
23.07078
0.5184
3
S1
-0.14461
0.08996
0.21068
0.53211
0.30117
-12.02201
0.5231
4
S2
-0.04587
0.05542
0.20342
0.31348
0.22407
21.23889
0.5171
5
S3
-0.01793
0.42558
0.21272
0.55329
0.07899
-33.44582
0.4838
6
P
0.00492
0.00730
0.19940
0.15338
0.09913
46.08075
0.2507
7
DI
0.07114
0.20676
0.09848
0.23259
0.32429
3.07933
0.8982
Panel B: Optimistic Scenario of Globalization
1
E1
0.12400
0.10555
0.07432
0.20298
-0.06958
42.89204
0.2417
2
E2
0.09679
0.23024
-0.02864
0.24574
0.05692
26.76866
0.5184
3
S1
-0.16699
0.12057
0.22784
0.48374
0.30252
-8.67294
0.5180
4
S2
-0.07373
0.08948
0.19270
0.30243
0.20114
25.23083
0.5035
5
S3
-0.06626
0.45089
0.36109
0.43824
0.11419
-30.03597
0.4843
6
P
0.06859
0.01120
0.17536
0.21128
-0.04321
52.97000
0.2898
7
DI
0.07114
0.20676
0.09848
0.23259
0.32429
3.07933
0.8982
Notes: Numbers in the table are coefficients of predictor variables estimated by OLS technique. Panel A pertains to globalization with pessimistic scenario, while panel B displays estimation with optimistic scenario. For descriptions of abbreviated variables see table 1. Equation numbers correspond to equations 1-7 explained in section 3.
At the second stage, we estimate the structural parameters (A and B) by OLS (i.e. conventional 2-SLS) and present them in table 3 where Panel A and Panel B correspond to pessimistic and optimistic views respectively. As the proposed alternative at the second stage, we also estimate the structural parameters by Shapley value regression and present them in table 4 (pessimistic and optimistic views at Panel A and B respectively). It may be noted that obtaining the coefficients of the Shapley value regression we have to use an efficient optimization method (Lipovetsky, 2006; Mishra, 2016). In the present study, this is done by the Host-Parasite Co-Evolutionary algorithm, which is a powerful biologically inspired population method of global optimization (Mishra, 2013). In table 3 and table 4, the current endogenous parameters matrix (A) has in the principal diagonal cells minus unity which pertains to the dependent endogenous variable in the equation concerned. A zero in an off-diagonal cell denotes that the endogenous variable is not included in the particular equation. Similarly, in B matrix, a zero in a cell denotes that the particular predetermined variable is not included in the equation concerned.
Moreover, we also report standard errors of estimate of the coefficients corresponding to the Shapley value based 2-SLS structural coefficients reported in table 4 using Jackknife resampling technique. For both (Panel A and B) the t-value for all endogenous (but none of the predetermined) predictors are statistically significant at 1% level.
Table 3. Estimated Structural Parameters Based on Conventional 2-SLS Estimation
Eqs. No.
Endogenous Variables (Transposed A Matrix)
Predetermined Variables (Transposed B Matrix)
R2
E1
E2
S1
S2
S3
P
DI
EPP
FOG
PPN
PCL
CVL
CONST
Panel A: Pessimistic Scenario of Globalization
1
-1
0.7800
1.1911
0
0
0
0
0
-0.0910
0
-0.6100
-0.2760
19.6726
0.3753
2
0
-1
0
1.4254
0.5535
-3.5950
0
0.1899
0
0.3030
0
0
176.946
0.5184
3
1.6709
0
-1
0
-0.9450
0
0
0
0.0888
0
0.7528
0.2284
-82.6508
0.5231
4
0
-0.4740
0
-1
0
0
0
0
0.1919
0.2010
0.4090
0.2273
32.1631
0.5171
5
0
0
0
0
-1
0.7969
0
-0.0220
0.4198
0.0540
0.4311
0
-70.1672
0.4838
6
-0.2110
-0.6580
-0.8960
1.5482
0.5704
-1
0
0
0
0
0
0
41.6162
0.2507
7
0
0.2382
-2.363
6.0177
0.096
-3.2440
-1
0
0
0
0
0
-5.9572
0.8982
Panel B: Optimistic Scenario of Globalization
1
-1
2.3547
0.6222
0
0
0
0
0
-0.5116
0
-0.6766
-0.3918
-14.7428
0.2417
2
0
-1
0
0.0160
0.5052
0.0923
0
0.1251
0
-0.2303
0
0
36.6456
0.5184
3
-0.9095
0
-1
0
0.8182
0
0
0
-0.1523
0
0.3098
0.1458
54.9108
0.5180
4
0
-0.7618
0
-1
0
0
0
0
0.2649
0.1709
0.4896
0.2445
45.6232
0.5035
5
0
0
0
0
-1
-2.6429
0
0.1150
0.4805
0.8245
0.9966
0
109.9563
0.4843
6
1.2483
-0.6065
-0.0036
0.4164
-0.0394
-1
0
0
0
0
0
0
3.9434
0.2898
7
0
0.8967
-2.2264
4.6889
-0.3119
-0.9095
-1
0
0
0
0
0
-119.7295
0.8982
Notes: Numbers in the table are coefficients of predictor variables estimated by conventional 2-OLS technique. Panel A presents estimation of globalization with pessimistic scenario, while panel B displays estimation with optimistic scenario. For descriptions of abbreviated variables see table 1. Equation numbers corresponds to equations 1-7 explained in section 3.
Table 4. Estimated Structural Parameters Based on Shapley-Value Regression 2-SLS Estimation
Eqs. Endogenous Variables: Transposed A Matrix Predetermined Variables: Transposed B Matrix R2 E1 E2 S1 S2 S3 P DI EPP FOG PPN PCL CVL CONST Panel A: Pessimistic view 0.2246***
0.1801***
0.1058
0.1413
0.0857
-41.2332
1
-
(0.0346)
(0.0265)
-
-
-
-
-
(0.2062)
-
(0.1769)
(0.1334)
(5.6861)
0.3618
[6.4913]
[6.7962]
[0.5131]
[0.7988]
[0.6424]
[-7.2516]
0.1921***
0.1235***
0.2956***
0.0669
0.1025
-47.4994
2
-
-
-
(0.0200)
(0.0173)
(0.0316)
-
(0.1249)
-
(0.1418)
-
-
(4.8967)
0.4803
[9.605]
[7.1387]
[9.3544]
[0.5356]
[0.7228]
[-9.7003]
0.3173***
0.1711***
0.1374
0.2075
0.1146
-52.7262
3
(0.0245)
-
-
-
(0.0141)
-
-
-
(0.1407)
-
(0.1916)
(0.1970)
(4.9762)
0.5040
[12.951]
[12.1348]
[0.9765]
[1.0830]
[0.5817]
[-10.5957]
0.2622***
0.1158
0.1397
0.1682
0.1077
-45.3551
4
-
(0.0265)
-
-
-
-
-
-
(0.1414)
(0.2119)
(0.2010)
(0.1581)
(3.7463)
0.5058
[9.8943]
[0.8190]
[0.6593]
[0.8368]
[0.6812]
[-12.1066]
0.6622***
0.1198
0.2281
0.2233
0.2903
-95.9363
5
-
-
-
-
-
(0.0872)
-
(0.2107)
(0.3092)
(0.3342)
(0.3822)
-
(10.7596)
0.4653
[7.594]
[0.5686]
[0.7377]
[0.6682]
[0.7595]
[-8.9163]
0.1334***
0.1300***
0.0993***
0.1444***
0.0706***
-31.8045
6
(0.0224)
(0.0245)
(0.0173)
(0.0316)
(0.0141)
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
(5.2208)
0.2392
[5.9554]
[5.3061]
[5.7399]
[4.5696]
[5.0071]
[-6.0919]
0.3241***
0.2197***
0.2931***
0.1585***
0.4340***
-84.8041
7
-
(0.0141)
(0.0100)
(0.0100)
(0.0058)
(0.0173)
-
-
-
-
-
-
(3.1439)
0.8480
[22.9858]
[21.9700]
[29.3100]
[27.3276]
[25.0867]
[-26.9742]
Panel B: Optimistic view 0.1783***
0.1106***
0.0740
0.0929
0.0614
-30.2465
1
-
(0.0363)
(0.0239)
-
-
-
-
-
(0.1470)
-
(0.1685)
(0.1193)
(5.1579)
0.2295
[4.9118]
[4.6276]
[0.5034]
[0.5513]
[0.5147]
[-5.8641]
0.2071***
0.1157***
0.3142***
0.0693
0.1051
-51.7940
2
-
-
-
(0.0197)
(0.0126)
(0.0339)
-
(0.1516)
-
(0.1204)
-
-
(5.0830)
0.4816
[10.5127]
[9.1825]
[9.2684]
[0.4571]
[0.8729]
[-10.1897]
0.4186***
0.1708***
0.1327
0.2071
0.1117
-62.6993
3
(0.0386)
-
-
-
(0.0141)
-
-
-
(0.1497)
-
(0.2334)
(0.2075)
(6.1482)
0.4950
[10.8446]
[12.1135]
[0.8864]
[0.8873]
[0.5383]
[-10.198]
0.2502***
0.1087
0.1289
0.1635
0.0969
-44.1332
4
-
(0.0240)
-
-
-
-
-
-
(0.1337)
(0.2028)
(0.1855)
(0.1367)
(3.7357)
0.4922
[10.425]
[0.8130]
[0.6356]
[0.8814]
[0.7089]
[-11.8139]
0.7641***
0.1297
0.2512
0.2468
0.2919
-109.4473
5
-
-
-
-
-
(0.0753)
-
(0.2202)
(0.3311)
(0.3410)
(0.3301)
-
(10.224)
0.4720
[10.1474]
[0.5890]
[0.7587]
[0.7238]
[0.8843]
[-10.7049]
0.1968***
0.1237***
0.0862***
0.1179***
0.0599***
-35.4534
6
(0.0405)
(0.0178)
(0.0156)
(0.0210)
(0.0100)
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
(5.3336)
0.2735
[4.8593]
[6.9494]
[5.5256]
[5.6143]
[5.9900]
[-6.6472]
0.3319***
0.2273***
0.3195***
0.1487***
0.4421***
-92.4873
7
-
(0.0136)
(0.0115)
(0.0160)
(0.0058)
(0.0209)
-
-
-
-
-
-
(3.3760)
0.8358
[24.4044]
[19.7652]
[19.9688]
[25.6379]
[21.1531]
[-27.3955]
Notes: Numbers in the table are coefficients of predictor variabled estimated by Shapley Value Regression 2-SLS technique; their standard errors and t-statistics are presented in parentheses and brackets respectively. The standard errors are derived by Jackknife resampling technique. Panel A presents estimation of globalization with pessimistic scenario, while panel B displays estimation with optimistic scenario. For descriptions of abbreviated variables see table 1. Equation numbers corresponds to equations 1-7 explained in section 3.
In the last column of tables 2-4, the R2 values are reported corresponding to each equation. We observe that conventional 2-SLS at the second stage gives the R2 values that are identical to those obtained for the reduced form equations. However, the R2 values for the proposed 2-SLS (in which OLS is replaced by the Shapley value regression) are a little smaller than those given by the conventional 2-SLS based on OLS. This cost has to be paid for treating the collinearity problem that has devastating effects on the coefficients of the structural equations.
Interpretation
In table 5 we present the Shapley value shares of the predictor variables (in R2) in different equations of the model for pessimistic and optimistic scenarios, respectively. Their percentage shares in the respective R2 also are reported. A zero value in a cell(i,j) indicates that the jth predictor variable is absent in the ith equation. The symbol (-) in the principal diagonal cells is the cell for the ith dependent endogenous variable appearing in the ith equation.
As to the significance of the Shapley share of a particular predictor in R2, the statistical tests (reported in table 4, though) are not yet well established. Nevertheless, as a thumb rule (which could be very robust) we may state that if R2 is statistically significant (at, say, 1 percent level and the appropriate degrees of freedom) and there are k predictors, then 100/k is the most reasonable share (percentage) that could be attributed to any particular predictor when we have no knowledge of its factual contribution. This is based on the Principle of Insufficient Reason or the Principle of Indifference (Keynes, 1921, pp. 44-70), when no reason is known to distribute the shares differently. On this logic, whenever the share of a predictor variable (5 in number in each equation) is 20 percent or more, it is surely significant. It may be noted that R2 for all equations are significant at 1 percent. We use this thumb rule and accordingly we have underlined (in table 5) the percentage contribution of those predictors that are not less than 20 percent.
A simple analysis is presented in table 6. Equation-wise, we present the list of predictor variables that have Shapley value shares 20% or more within square brackets [.], those having Shapley value shares not less than 19 percent but less than 20 percent in curly brackets {.} and those having Shapley value shares not less than 18 percent but less than 19 percent in round brackets (.). We do not consider below 18 percent contribution. The symbol U stands for the ‘union’ set operator. Accordingly, we may assign the importance of the predictor variable. The lists are not identical in the two scenarios. But in any case, the bi-directional causality between democracy and globalization is established. The globalization variables E2 (relaxation of restrictions on trans-border trade as well as capital movement by means of taxation, tariff, etc.) and S2 (flow of information) surely affect democratization (DI16). Among the exogenous (predetermined) variables, CVL (Civil liberties) is a weak and EPP (Electoral process and pluralism) is a very weak predictor.
Table 5. Shapley-Value Shares of Predictors in R2 and their Percentage
Eqs. No.
Endogenous Variables (Transposed A Matrix)
Predetermined Variables (Transposed B Matrix)
E1
E2
S1
S2
S3
P
DI
EPP
FOG
PPN
PCL
CVL
CONST
Panel A: Pessimistic Scenario of Globalization
1
-
0.0836
(22.26%)
0.0949
(25.28%)
-
-
-
-
-
0.0768
(20.46%)
-
0.0663
(17.65%)
0.0538
(14.35%)
0.3753
(100%)
2
-
-
-
0.1135
(21.89%)
0.1317
(25.40%)
0.1081
(20.85%)
-
0.0849
(16.38%)
-
0.0802
(15.47%)
-
-
0.5184
(100%)
3
0.1233
(23.58%)
-
-
-
0.1253
(23.96%)
-
-
-
0.0894
(17.09%)
-
0.1113
(21.29%)
0.0737
(14.09%)
0.5231
(100%)
4
-
0.1190
(23.01%)
-
-
-
-
-
-
0.0955
(18.46%)
0.1076
(20.81%)
0.1017
(19.67%)
0.0933
(18.04%)
0.5171
(100%)
5
-
-
-
-
-
0.1180
(24.38%)
-
0.0590
(12.20%)
0.1174
(24.26%)
0.0860
(17.77%)
0.1035
(21.38%)
-
0.4838
(100%)
6
0.0486
(19.38%)
0.0458
(18.25%)
0.0493
(19.67%)
0.0595
(23.73%)
0.0476
(18.97%)
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
0.2508
(100%)
7
-
0.1952
(21.73%)
0.1661
(18.50%)
0.1880
(20.93%)
0.1697
(18.89%)
0.1792
(19.95%)
-
-
-
-
-
-
0.8982
(100%)
Panel B: Optimistic Scenario of Globalization
1
-
0.0632
(26.14%)
0.0513
(21.21%)
-
-
-
-
-
0.0490
(20.25%)
-
0.0401
(16.58%)
0.0382
(15.82%)
0.2417
(100%)
2
-
-
-
0.1171
(22.59%)
0.1282
(24.74%)
0.1023
(19.73%)
-
0.0895
(17.27%)
-
0.0813
(15.68%)
-
-
0.5184
(100%)
3
0.1096
(21.16%)
-
-
-
0.1334
(25.76%)
-
-
-
0.0899
(17.35%)
-
0.1120
(21.63%)
0.073
(14.1%)
0.5180
(100%)
4
-
0.1187
(23.57%)
-
-
-
-
-
-
0.0946
(18.80%)
0.1012
(20.10%)
0.1060
(21.05%)
0.083
(16.48%)
0.5035
(100%)
5
-
-
-
-
-
0.1155
(23.86%)
-
0.0619
(12.79%)
0.1219
(25.18%)
0.0934
(19.28%)
0.0915
(18.89%)
-
0.4843
(100%)
6
0.0667
(23.00%)
0.0548
(18.92%)
0.0547
(18.86%)
0.0576
(19.89%)
0.0560
(19.32%)
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
0.2898
(100%)
7
-
0.2041
(22.72%)
0.1729
(19.25%)
0.1922
(21.40%)
0.1731
(19.27%)
0.1559
(17.36%)
-
-
-
-
-
-
0.8982
(100%)
Notes: The numbers in the table are shares of predictor variables (estimated by Shapley Value decomposition) in 2-SLS R2, while their percentage weights are given in the parentheses. We have distinguished the ones whose percentage contribution in R2 is more than 20% by underlining them. Panel A presents estimation of globalization with pessimistic scenario, while panel B displays estimation with optimistic scenario. For descriptions of abbreviated variables see table 1. Equation numbers corresponds to equations 1-7 explained in section 3.
Table 6. Equation-wise Strength of Predictor Variables According to the Shapley Value Shares
Equations
Pessimistic Scenario
Optimistic Scenario
1
E1=f([E2, S1, FOG] U {null} U (null))
E1=f([E2, S1, FOG] U {null} U (null))
2
E2=f([S2, S3, P] U {null} U (null))
E2=f([S2, S3] U {P} U (null))
3
S1=f([E1,S3,PCL] U{null} U (null))
S1=f([E1,S3,PCL] U{null} U (null))
4
S2=f([E2, PPN] U {PCL } U (FOG, CVL))
S2=f([E2, PPN, PCL] U {FOG} U (null))
5
S3=f([P, FOG, PCL] U {null} U (null))
S3=f([P, FOG] U {PPN} U (PCL))
6
P=f([S2] U {E1, S1} U (E2, S3))
P=f([E1] U {S2, S3} U (E2, S1))
7
DI16 =f([E2, S2] U {P} U (S1, S3))
DI16 =f([E2, S2] U {S1, S3} U (null))
Notes: [.] > 20%; 19% < {.} < 20%; 18% < (.) < 19%; we do not consider below 18% contribution. The symbol U stands for the “union” set operator. Equation numbers corresponds to equations 1-7 explained in section 3.
In table 7 we present the list of predictor variables (equation-wise) that have negatively signed structural coefficients estimated by the conventional 2-SLS. In the first equation (for E1) the democracy measures FOG (Functioning of Government), PCL (political Culture) and CVL (Civil Liberties) have negative sign. This is for both pessimistic and optimistic views of globalization. In the second equation P (political measure of globalization) or PPN (Political Participation) adversely affect E2 (relaxation of constraints on trans-border flow of goods, services and finance). In equation #3 trans-border personal contacts (S1) are adversely affected by cultural proximity (S3), trans-border flow of goods, services and finance (E1) or the Functioning of the Government (FOG). In equation #4, follow of information (S2) is adversely affected by relaxation of restrictions on trans-border trade and flow of finance (E2). In equation #4, cultural proximity (S3) is adversely affected by electoral process and pluralism (EPP) or political set up for enhancing globalization (P). In equation #6, the political set up for enhancing globalization is adversely affected by trans-border flow of goods, services and finance (E1), relaxation for restrictions on trans-border trade etc. (E2), trans- border personal contacts and movement of people (S1) or trans-border cultural proximity (S3). It may be noted that most of these (negative) relationships are unexpected and misleading. They also indicate that different measures of globalization are not in concordance with each other. As to the final equation (#7 for DI16), trans-border personal contacts and movement of people (S1), political set up for promoting globalization (P) and/or cultural proximity (S3) adversely affect democratization.
Table 7. Predictor Variables that obtain Negatively Signed Structural Coefficients Estimated by the Conventional 2-SLS
Endogenous (Dependent) Variable
Pessimistic Scenario
of Globalization
Optimistic Scenario
of Globalization
Equations
Predictor Variables
Predictor Variables
Endogenous
Predetermined
Endogenous
Predetermined
1
E1
-
FOG, PCl, CVL
-
FOG, PCl, CVL
2
E2
P
-
-
PPN
3
S1
S3
-
E1
FOG
4
S2
E2
-
E2
-
5
S3
-
EPP
P
-
6
P
E1, E2, S1
-
E2, S1, S3
-
7
DI16
S1, P
-
S1, S3, P
-
Notes: Panel A presents estimation of globalization with pessimistic scenario, while panel B displays estimation with optimistic scenario. For descriptions of abbreviated variables see table 1. Equation numbers corresponds to equations 1-7 explained in section 3.
In contrast, a perusal of table 4 (the structural coefficient matrices A’ and B’ obtained by the proposed Shapley value regression at the second stage) suggests that the coefficients associated with endogenous as well as predetermined variables (except constant terms) are all positive. They suggest that globalization measures are concordant with each other and the democratic regimes promote globalization. We also find that DI16 is positively affected by all predictor variables included in equation #7, indicating that globalization promotes democratization.
The contrasting results obtained by the conventional 2-SLS and the proposed Shapley value based 2-SLS indicate that neither data nor the specification in our model were responsible for the unexpected results provided by the conventional 2-SLS, but the problem was created by collinearity at the second stage of the 2- SLS. A treatment of the problem of collinearity by using the Shapley value regression at the second stage of 2-SLS has rendered the results that are conformal to our expectation based on reasoned and realistic ground.
In table 8 we present the correlation matrices of disturbances across the equations. A larger magnitude of correlation in an off-diagonal cell indicates cross correlation of residuals that may affect the efficiency of an equation method of estimation and prompt to seek for an application of any system method of estimation such as 3-SLS or FIML. A perusal of the elements of correlation matrices reveals that while for DI16 the cross correlations are often very small (irrespective of the view of globalization - pessimistic or optimistic, and the method of estimation - conventional or Shapley value regression based), this is only partially (but dominantly) true of P (the political dimension of globalization). However, this is not so for the economic (E1 and E2) and social (S1, S2 and S3) indicators of globalization in which most of the correlation coefficients are significantly large in magnitude.
Table 8. Correlation Among Residuals at Stage-2 of Conventional and Shapley Value Based 2-SLS
Eqs. No.
End. Var.
Conventional 2-SLS
Shapley Value based 2-SLS
E1
E2
S1
S2
S3
P
DI16
E1
E2
S1
S2
S3
P
DI16
Panel A: Pessimistic Scenario of Globalization
1
E1
1
0.387
0.575
0.560
0.280
-0.186
0.066
1
0.354
0.564
0.551
0.274
-0.180
0.008
2
E2
0.387
1
0.517
0.563
0.472
-0.021
0.072
0.354
1
0.458
0.509
0.479
-0.050
0.073
3
S1
0.575
0.517
1
0.660
0.466
-0.199
0.038
0.564
0.458
1
0.669
0.456
-0.189
-0.041
4
S2
0.560
0.563
0.660
1
0.543
0.098
-0.056
0.551
0.509
0.669
1
0.529
0.103
-0.087
5
S3
0.280
0.472
0.466
0.543
1
0.390
-0.047
0.274
0.479
0.456
0.529
1
0.359
-0.102
6
P
-0.186
-0.021
-0.199
0.098
0.390
1
0.078
-0.180
-0.050
-0.189
0.103
0.359
1
0.085
7
DI16
0.066
0.072
0.038
-0.056
-0.047
0.078
1
0.008
0.073
-0.041
-0.087
-0.102
0.085
1
Panel B: Optimistic Scenario of Globalization
1
E1
1
0.347
0.553
0.509
0.205
-0.224
0.139
1
0.315
0.526
0.494
0.187
-0.204
0.097
2
E2
0.347
1
0.528
0.599
0.479
-0.016
0.071
0.315
1
0.476
0.556
0.475
-0.048
0.093
3
S1
0.553
0.528
1
0.696
0.512
-0.141
0.004
0.526
0.476
1
0.704
0.509
-0.130
-0.081
4
S2
0.509
0.599
0.696
1
0.586
0.107
-0.005
0.494
0.556
0.704
1
0.582
0.111
-0.068
5
S3
0.205
0.479
0.512
0.586
1
0.319
-0.053
0.187
0.475
0.509
0.582
1
0.297
-0.077
6
P
-0.224
-0.016
-0.141
0.107
0.319
1
0.134
-0.204
-0.048
-0.130
0.111
0.297
1
0.066
7
DI16
0.139
0.071
0.004
-0.005
-0.053
0.134
1
0.097
0.093
-0.081
-0.068
-0.077
0.066
1
Notes: Numbers in the table are correlation coefficients among residuals of conventional 2-SLS vis-á- vis Shapley Value 2-SLS. For descriptions of abbreviated variables see table 1. Equation numbers corresponds to equations 1-7 explained in section 3.
In table 9 we present the difference between the cross-equation correlation coefficients obtained by the conventional and the Shapley value based 2-SLS. This is for both views of globalization, pessimistic and optimistic. A positive value in the off-diagonal cell indicates that the cross-equation correlation of disturbances obtained by the conventional 2-SLS is stronger than the one obtained by the Shapley value regression based 2-SLS (while the negative value conveys the opposite). For the pessimistic view of globalization, in the upper diagonal cells of the difference matrix 21 (=7x(7-1)/2) elements are there. Out of them only 7 are negative. It conveys that in two-third of cases the Shapley value based 2-SLS may be more efficient than the conventional 2-SLS. For the optimistic view of globalization, there are only 5 negative values in the upper diagonal cells of the difference matrix. It conveys that in (a little over) three-fourth of cases, the Shapley value based 2-SLS may be more efficient than the conventional 2-SLS. This also is one of the reasons why we consider that the Shapley value based 2-SLS has given better results than the conventional 2-SLS.
Table 9. Difference between Correlation Among Residuals of Conventional versus Shapley Value Based 2-SLS
Eqs. No.
End. Var.
Pessimistic Scenario of Globalization
Optimistic Scenario of Globalization
E1
E2
S1
S2
S3
P
DI16
E1
E2
S1
S2
S3
P
DI16
Panel A: Pessimistic Scenario of Globalization
1
E1
0
0.033
0.011
0.009
0.006
-0.006
0.058
0
0.032
0.027
0.015
0.018
-0.02
0.042
2
E2
0.033
0
0.059
0.054
-0.007
0.029
-0.001
0.032
0
0.052
0.043
0.004
0.032
-0.022
3
S1
0.011
0.059
0
-0.009
0.01
-0.01
0.079
0.027
0.052
0
-0.008
0.003
-0.011
0.085
4
S2
0.009
0.054
-0.009
0
0.014
-0.005
0.031
0.015
0.043
-0.008
0
0.004
-0.004
0.063
5
S3
0.006
-0.007
0.01
0.014
0
0.031
0.055
0.018
0.004
0.003
0.004
0
0.022
0.024
6
P
-0.006
0.029
-0.01
-0.005
0.031
0
-0.007
-0.02
0.032
-0.011
-0.004
0.022
0
0.068
7
DI16
0.058
-0.001
0.079
0.031
0.055
-0.007
0
0.042
-0.022
0.085
0.063
0.024
0.068
0
Notes: Numbers in the table are difference of correlation coefficients among residuals of conventional and Shapley Value 2-SLS. For descriptions of abbreviated variables see table 1. Equation numbers corresponds to equations 1-7 explained in section 3.
Concluding Remarks
On the basis of our analysis that models the relationship between democracy and globalization in a simultaneous equations framework, we conclude the following counts. First, democracy and globalization promote each other and hence there is a bi-directional causality with positive relationships running both ways between democracy and globalization as envisaged by Eichengreen and Leblang (2006). At a national level, there may be various intermediary conditions (such as institutional and historical factors, relative factor abundance, demographic reasons, influence and the self-interests of the elite class, safety nets for stability and building political support by the national government, etc.) that modify the relationship as well as set in motion a complex of positive and/or negative feedbacks to accelerate or retard the pace of globalization and democratization in a country-specific manner. However, when a large number of countries are studied a clear relationship emerges out.
Second, there is a need to estimate the structural coefficients of the model cautiously since the regression equations may be suffering from collinearity among the predictor variables. The Shapley value regression based 2-SLS has performed better than the conventional regression in estimating the structural parameters of the model.
Third, it is expected that the system methods of estimation of the model would give better results than what are obtained by the single equation methods of estimation of structural parameters of the model.
References
Acemoglu, D., and Robinson, J.A. (2006a). Economic Backwardness in Political Perspective. American Political Science Review, 100(1), 115-131.
Acemoglu, D., and Robinson, J.A. (2006b). Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. Cambridge, Mass: Cambridge University Press.
Dreher, A. (2006). Does Globalization Affect Growth? Evidence from a new Index of Globalization. Applied Economics, 38(10), 1091-1110.
Dreher, A., Gaston, N., and Martens, P. (2008). Measuring Globalisation: Gauging its Consequences. New York: Springer.
Eichengreen, B., and Leblang, D. (2006). Democracy and Globalization. NBER Working Paper, No. 12450. Cambridge, Mass: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Haffoudhi, H., and Bellakhal, R. (2016). Threshold Effect of Globalization on Democracy: The Role of Demography. SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2906308.
Hayek, F.A. (1960). The Constitution of Liberty. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Keynes, J.M. (1921). A Treatise on Probability. London: Macmillan.
Kollias, C., and Paleologou, S.M. (2016). Globalization and Democracy: A Disaggregated Analysis by Income Group. Global Economy Journal, 16(2), 213–228.
Li, Q., and Reuveny, R. (2003). Economic Globalization and Democracy: An Empirical Analysis. British Journal of Political Science, 33(1), 29-54.
Lipovetsky, S. (2006). Entropy Criterion in Logistic Regression and Shapley Value of Predictors. Journal of Modern Applied Statistical Methods, 5(1), 95-106.
Lipset, S.M. (1959). Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic Development and Political Legitimacy. American Political Science Review, 53(1), 69-105.
Milner, H.V. and Mukherjee, B. (2009). Democratization and Economic Globalization. Annual Review Political Science, 12, 163–81.
Mishra, S.K. (2013). Global Optimization of Some Difficult Benchmark Functions by Host-Parasite Coevolutionary Algorithm. Economics Bulletin, 33(1), 1-18.
Mishra, S.K. (2016). Shapley Value Regression and the Resolution of Multicollinearity. Journal of Economics Bibliography, 3(3), 498-515.
Mishra, S.K. (2017). Almost Equi-Marginal Principle based Composite Index of Globalization: China, India and Pakistan. Journal of Economic and Social Thought, 4(3), 335-351.
Nayyar, D. (1915). Globalization and Democracy. Brazilian Journal of Political Economy, 35 (3), 388-402.
Reiersol, O. (1945). Confluence Analysis by Means of Instrumental Sets of Variables. Arkiv for Mathematic, Astronomi, och Fysik. 32A. Uppsala: Almquist & Wiksells.
Roth, A.E. (1988). Introduction to the Shapley Value. In Roth, A.E. (ed. 1977). The Shapley Value: Essays in Honor of Lloyd S. Shapley. New York: Cambridge Univ. Press.
Rudra, N. (2005). Globalization and the Strengthening of Democracy in the Developing World. American Journal of Political Science, 49(4), 704-730.
Schumpter, J.A. (1950). Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.
Schwartzman, K.C. (1998). Globalization and democracy. Annual Review of Sociology, 24(1), 159-81.
Smith, G., and Brainard, W. (1976). The Value of a priori Information in Estimating a Financial Model. Journal of Finance, 31(5), 1299-1322.
Sobhan, R. (2003). Globalization and the Challenge to Democracy. International Journal of Development Issues, 2(2), 1-14.
Stein, A.A. (2016). The Great Trilemma: Are Globalization, Democracy, and Sovereignty Compatible? International Theory, 8(2), 297-340.
Steiner, N.D. (2015). Essays on Globalization and Democracy. D. Phil dissertation, vorgelegt dem Fachbereich 02 – Sozialwissenschaften, Medien und Sport der Johannes Gutenberg Univ., Mainz. https://nilssteiner.com/wp- content/uploads/2017/01/Dissertation_Steiner_Introduction-only.pdf
Turyahikayo, E. (2014). The Impact of Globalization on Domestic Political Structures in Established, Transitional and Non-Democracies. Journal of Good Governance and Sustainable Development in Africa, 2(2), 94-109.
Appendix
Table A1. Scores Obtained by Countries on the Measures in Different Dimensions of Democracy
Country | Dimensions of Democracy – 2006 | Democracy Index 2016 (DI16) | |||||
EPP | FOG | PPN | PCL | CVL | |||
1 | Albania | 7.33 | 5.07 | 4.44 | 5.63 | 7.06 | 5.91 |
2 | Algeria | 2.25 | 2.21 | 2.22 | 5.63 | 3.53 | 3.56 |
3 | Argentina | 8.75 | 5 | 5.56 | 5.63 | 8.24 | 6.96 |
4 | Australia | 10 | 8.93 | 7.78 | 8.75 | 10 | 9.01 |
5 | Austria | 9.58 | 8.21 | 7.78 | 8.75 | 9.12 | 8.41 |
6 | Azerbaijan | 3.08 | 0.79 | 3.33 | 3.75 | 5.59 | 2.65 |
7 | Belgium | 9.58 | 8.21 | 6.67 | 6.88 | 9.41 | 7.77 |
8 | Benin | 6.83 | 6.43 | 3.89 | 6.88 | 6.76 | 5.67 |
9 | Bhutan | 0.08 | 4.64 | 1.11 | 3.75 | 3.53 | 4.93 |
10 | Bolivia | 8.33 | 5.71 | 4.44 | 3.75 | 7.65 | 5.63 |
11 | Botswana | 9.17 | 7.86 | 5 | 6.88 | 9.12 | 7.87 |
12 | Brazil | 9.58 | 7.86 | 4.44 | 5.63 | 9.41 | 6.9 |
13 | Bulgaria | 9.58 | 5.71 | 6.67 | 5 | 8.53 | 7.01 |
14 | Burkina Faso | 4 | 1.79 | 2.78 | 5.63 | 4.41 | 4.7 |
15 | Burundi | 4.42 | 3.29 | 3.89 | 6.25 | 4.71 | 2.4 |
16 | C.Africa Rep. | 0.42 | 1.43 | 1.67 | 1.88 | 2.65 | 1.61 |
17 | Cambodia | 5.58 | 6.07 | 2.78 | 5 | 4.41 | 4.27 |
18 | Cameroon | 0.92 | 3.21 | 2.78 | 5.63 | 3.82 | 3.46 |
19 | Canada | 9.17 | 9.64 | 7.78 | 8.75 | 10 | 9.15 |
20 | Chad | 0 | 0 | 0 | 5 | 3.24 | 1.5 |
21 | Chile | 9.58 | 8.93 | 5 | 6.25 | 9.71 | 7.78 |
22 | China | 0 | 4.64 | 2.78 | 6.25 | 1.18 | 3.14 |
23 | Colombia | 9.17 | 4.36 | 5 | 4.38 | 9.12 | 6.67 |
24 | Congo D. Rep. | 4.58 | 0.36 | 2.78 | 3.75 | 2.35 | 1.93 |
25 | Congo Rep. | 4.58 | 0.36 | 2.78 | 3.75 | 2.35 | 2.91 |
26 | Costa Rica | 9.58 | 8.21 | 6.11 | 6.88 | 9.41 | 7.88 |
27 | Cyprus | 9.17 | 6.79 | 6.67 | 6.25 | 9.12 | 7.65 |
28 | Denmark | 10 | 9.64 | 8.89 | 9.38 | 9.71 | 9.2 |
29 | Dominic Rep. | 9.17 | 4.29 | 3.33 | 5.63 | 8.24 | 6.67 |
30 | Ecuador | 7.83 | 4.29 | 5 | 3.13 | 7.94 | 5.81 |
31 | Egypt | 2.67 | 3.64 | 2.78 | 6.88 | 3.53 | 3.31 |
32 | El Salvador | 9.17 | 5.43 | 3.89 | 4.38 | 8.24 | 6.64 |
33 | Ethiopia | 4 | 3.93 | 5 | 6.25 | 4.41 | 3.6 |
34 | Fiji | 6.5 | 5.21 | 3.33 | 5 | 8.24 | 5.64 |
35 | Finland | 10 | 10 | 7.78 | 8.75 | 9.71 | 9.03 |
36 | France | 9.58 | 7.5 | 6.67 | 7.5 | 9.12 | 7.92 |
37 | Gabon | 0.5 | 3.21 | 2.22 | 5.63 | 2.06 | 3.74 |
38 | Gambia | 4 | 4.64 | 4.44 | 5.63 | 3.24 | 2.91 |
39 | Germany | 9.58 | 8.57 | 7.78 | 8.75 | 9.41 | 8.63 |
40 | Ghana | 7.42 | 4.64 | 4.44 | 4.38 | 5.88 | 6.75 |
41 | Greece | 9.58 | 7.5 | 6.67 | 7.5 | 9.41 | 7.23 |
42 | Guatemala | 8.75 | 6.79 | 2.78 | 4.38 | 7.65 | 5.92 |
43 | Guinea | 1 | 0.79 | 2.22 | 3.75 | 2.35 | 3.14 |
44 | Guyana | 8.33 | 5.36 | 4.44 | 4.38 | 8.24 | 6.25 |
45 | Haiti | 5.58 | 3.64 | 2.78 | 2.5 | 6.47 | 4.02 |
46 | Honduras | 8.33 | 6.43 | 4.44 | 5 | 7.06 | 5.92 |
47 | Hungary | 9.58 | 6.79 | 5 | 6.88 | 9.41 | 6.72 |
48 | Iceland | 10 | 9.64 | 8.89 | 10 | 10 | 9.5 |
49 | India | 9.58 | 8.21 | 5.56 | 5.63 | 9.41 | 7.81 |
50 | Indonesia | 6.92 | 7.14 | 5 | 6.25 | 6.76 | 6.97 |
51 | Ireland | 9.58 | 8.93 | 7.78 | 8.75 | 10 | 9.15 |
52 | Israel | 9.17 | 6.64 | 7.78 | 7.5 | 5.29 | 7.85 |
53 | Italy | 9.17 | 6.43 | 6.11 | 8.13 | 8.82 | 7.98 |
54 | Ivory Coast | 1.25 | 2.86 | 3.33 | 5.63 | 3.82 | 3.81 |
55 | Jamaica | 9.17 | 7.14 | 5 | 6.25 | 9.12 | 7.39 |
56 | Japan | 9.17 | 7.86 | 5.56 | 8.75 | 9.41 | 7.99 |
57 | Jordan | 3.08 | 3.79 | 3.89 | 5 | 3.82 | 3.96 |
58 | Kenya | 4.33 | 4.29 | 5.56 | 6.25 | 5 | 5.33 |
59 | Kuwait | 1.33 | 4.14 | 1.11 | 5.63 | 3.24 | 3.85 |
60 | Lebanon | 7.92 | 2.36 | 6.11 | 6.25 | 6.47 | 4.86 |
61 | Lesotho | 7.92 | 6.43 | 4.44 | 6.25 | 7.35 | 6.59 |
62 | Luxembourg | 10 | 9.29 | 7.78 | 8.75 | 9.71 | 8.81 |
63 | Madagascar | 5.67 | 5.71 | 5.56 | 6.88 | 5.29 | 5.07 |
64 | Malawi | 6 | 5 | 3.89 | 4.38 | 5.59 | 5.55 |
65 | Malaysia | 6.08 | 5.71 | 4.44 | 7.5 | 6.18 | 6.54 |
66 | Mali | 8.25 | 5.71 | 3.89 | 5.63 | 6.47 | 5.7 |
67 | Malta | 9.17 | 8.21 | 6.11 | 8.75 | 9.71 | 8.39 |
68 | Mauritania | 1.83 | 4.29 | 2.22 | 3.13 | 4.12 | 3.96 |
69 | Mauritius | 9.17 | 8.21 | 5 | 8.13 | 9.71 | 8.28 |
70 | Mexico | 8.75 | 6.07 | 5 | 5 | 8.53 | 6.47 |
71 | Moldova | 9.17 | 4.29 | 6.11 | 5 | 7.94 | 6.01 |
72 | Mongolia | 9.17 | 6.07 | 3.89 | 5.63 | 8.24 | 6.62 |
73 | Montenegro | 9.17 | 5.71 | 5 | 5.63 | 7.35 | 5.72 |
74 | Morocco | 3.5 | 3.79 | 2.78 | 5.63 | 3.82 | 4.77 |
75 | Myanmar | 0 | 1.79 | 0.56 | 5.63 | 0.88 | 4.2 |
76 | Nepal | 0.08 | 3.57 | 2.22 | 5.63 | 5.59 | 4.86 |
77 | Netherlands | 9.58 | 9.29 | 9.44 | 10 | 10 | 8.8 |
78 | New Zealand | 10 | 8.57 | 8.33 | 8.13 | 10 | 9.26 |
79 | Nicaragua | 8.25 | 5.71 | 3.33 | 3.75 | 7.35 | 4.81 |
80 | Niger | 5.25 | 1.14 | 1.67 | 3.75 | 5.88 | 3.96 |
81 | Nigeria | 3.08 | 1.86 | 4.44 | 4.38 | 3.82 | 4.5 |
82 | Norway | 10 | 9.64 | 10 | 8.13 | 10 | 9.93 |
83 | Pakistan | 4.33 | 5.36 | 0.56 | 4.38 | 5 | 4.33 |
84 | Panama | 9.58 | 7.14 | 5.56 | 5.63 | 8.82 | 7.13 |
85 | Paraguay | 7.92 | 5 | 5 | 4.38 | 8.53 | 6.27 |
86 | Peru | 8.75 | 3.29 | 5.56 | 5 | 7.94 | 6.65 |
87 | Philippines | 9.17 | 5.36 | 5 | 3.75 | 9.12 | 6.94 |
88 | Poland | 9.58 | 6.07 | 6.11 | 5.63 | 9.12 | 6.83 |
89 | Portugal | 9.58 | 8.21 | 6.11 | 7.5 | 9.41 | 7.86 |
90 | Romania | 9.58 | 6.07 | 6.11 | 5 | 8.53 | 6.62 |
91 | Rwanda | 3 | 3.57 | 2.22 | 5 | 5.29 | 3.07 |
92 | Saudi Arabia | 0 | 2.36 | 1.11 | 4.38 | 1.76 | 1.93 |
93 | Senegal | 7 | 5 | 3.33 | 5.63 | 5.88 | 6.21 |
94 | Sierra Leone | 5.25 | 2.21 | 2.22 | 3.75 | 4.41 | 4.55 |
95 | Singapore | 4.33 | 7.5 | 2.78 | 7.5 | 7.35 | 6.38 |
96 | South Africa | 8.75 | 7.86 | 7.22 | 6.88 | 8.82 | 7.41 |
97 | South Korea | 9.58 | 7.14 | 7.22 | 7.5 | 7.94 | 7.92 |
98 | Spain | 9.58 | 7.86 | 6.11 | 8.75 | 9.41 | 8.3 |
99 | Swaziland | 1.75 | 2.86 | 2.22 | 3.13 | 4.71 | 3.03 |
100 | Sweden | 10 | 10 | 10 | 9.38 | 10 | 9.39 |
101 | Switzerland | 9.58 | 9.29 | 7.78 | 8.75 | 9.71 | 9.09 |
102 | Syria | 0 | 1.79 | 1.67 | 6.88 | 1.47 | 1.43 |
103 | Tanzania | 6 | 3.93 | 5.06 | 5.63 | 5.29 | 5.76 |
104 | Thailand | 4.83 | 6.43 | 5 | 5.63 | 6.47 | 4.92 |
105 | Togo | 0 | 0.79 | 0.56 | 5.63 | 1.76 | 3.32 |
106 | Trinid &Tobago | 9.17 | 6.79 | 6.11 | 5.63 | 8.24 | 7.1 |
107 | Tunisia | 0 | 2.36 | 2.22 | 6.88 | 3.82 | 6.4 |
108 | Turkey | 7.92 | 6.79 | 4.44 | 3.75 | 5.59 | 5.04 |
109 | Uganda | 4.33 | 3.93 | 4.44 | 6.25 | 6.76 | 5.26 |
110 | United Kingdom | 9.58 | 8.57 | 5 | 8.13 | 9.12 | 8.36 |
111 | United States | 8.75 | 7.86 | 7.22 | 8.75 | 8.53 | 7.98 |
112 | Uruguay | 10 | 8.21 | 5 | 6.88 | 9.71 | 8.17 |
113 | Venezuela | 7 | 3.64 | 5.56 | 5 | 5.88 | 4.68 |
114 | Vietnam | 0.83 | 4.29 | 2.78 | 4.38 | 1.47 | 3.38 |
115 | Yemen | 2.67 | 2.71 | 2.78 | 4.38 | 2.35 | 2.07 |
116 | Zambia | 5.25 | 4.64 | 3.33 | 6.25 | 6.76 | 5.99 |
Table A2. Economic, Social and Political Dimensions and Overall Indices of Globalization in Different Countries
Country | Year-H | E1 | E2 | S1 | S2 | S3 | P | KOF | AEMC | |
1 | Albania | 2009 | 56.57 | 73 | 52.55 | 73.9 | 2.42 | 80.69 | 61.6 | 61.61 |
2 | Algeria | 2006 | 55.36 | 52.55 | 32.39 | 64.92 | 1.93 | 80.65 | 54 | 53.32 |
3 | Argentina | 2008 | 45.92 | 39.11 | 43.3 | 71.5 | 41.47 | 92.07 | 59.95 | 59.19 |
4 | Australia | 2007 | 74.79 | 81.24 | 73.4 | 87.55 | 94.03 | 89.71 | 83.8 | 84.03 |
5 | Austria | 2007 | 89.34 | 86.56 | 87.06 | 92.06 | 95.54 | 96.86 | 91.87 | 93.95 |
6 | Azerbaijan | 2007 | 67.38 | 63.7 | 37.92 | 77.61 | 34.96 | 54.01 | 57.02 | 54.69 |
7 | Belgium | 2007 | 96.71 | 82.81 | 81.94 | 96.39 | 91.22 | 97.67 | 92.41 | 93.75 |
8 | Benin | 2014 | 53.79 | 42.92 | 28.55 | 39.46 | 2.48 | 75.17 | 46.67 | 48.99 |
9 | Bhutan | 2014 | 60.64 | 56.77 | 46.83 | 45.54 | 6.87 | 38.85 | 43.58 | 47.07 |
10 | Bolivia | 2006 | 62.03 | 59.79 | 39.52 | 51.01 | 3.78 | 75.69 | 54.42 | 56.38 |
11 | Botswana | 2008 | 77.58 | 59.64 | 59.54 | 57.17 | 5.88 | 59.28 | 55.5 | 60.64 |
12 | Brazil | 2014 | 51.77 | 52.82 | 24.46 | 70.5 | 39.58 | 94.3 | 61.4 | 58.16 |
13 | Bulgaria | 2013 | 80.04 | 72.93 | 51.55 | 77.71 | 85.3 | 84.96 | 76.98 | 76.34 |
14 | Burkina Faso | 2014 | 59.67 | 46.84 | 19.43 | 44.62 | 2.17 | 76.88 | 48.69 | 49.12 |
15 | Burundi | 2014 | 23.53 | 33.37 | 21.02 | 37.22 | 3.1 | 62.17 | 35.04 | 34.79 |
16 | C. Africa Rep. | 2014 | 49.56 | 28.29 | 13.44 | 40.71 | 2.24 | 58.39 | 36.34 | 37.27 |
17 | Cambodia | 2014 | 85.86 | 50.76 | 29.52 | 48.48 | 1.31 | 62.36 | 50.69 | 54.22 |
18 | Cameroon | 2014 | 44.96 | 38.31 | 16.91 | 52.02 | 2.24 | 73.16 | 44.2 | 42.75 |
19 | Canada | 2007 | 76.2 | 82.03 | 80.78 | 94.74 | 96.09 | 92.91 | 87.15 | 87.51 |
20 | Chad | 2006 | 55.49 | 27.21 | 23.94 | 32.35 | 2.91 | 60.04 | 38.37 | 41.7 |
21 | Chile | 2007 | 82.68 | 87.08 | 41.25 | 77.69 | 41.18 | 87.67 | 74.31 | 72.77 |
22 | China | 2014 | 43.49 | 62.19 | 18.71 | 65.65 | 78.37 | 84.26 | 62.02 | 56.85 |
23 | Colombia | 2013 | 58.32 | 57.38 | 33.46 | 69.69 | 38.12 | 79.65 | 60.15 | 58.23 |
24 | Congo D. Rep. | 2013 | 69.13 | 37.26 | 6.23 | 43.38 | 1 | 62.03 | 41.67 | 42.31 |
25 | Congo Rep. | 2014 | 96.24 | 41.58 | 35.45 | 43.93 | 1.25 | 63.67 | 51.83 | 57.31 |
26 | Costa Rica | 2007 | 64.79 | 73.3 | 60.37 | 78.75 | 45.65 | 58.63 | 63.66 | 63.45 |
27 | Cyprus | 2008 | 93.5 | 84.06 | 88.1 | 95.69 | 93.84 | 78.36 | 87.32 | 89.36 |
28 | Denmark | 2007 | 87.8 | 89.09 | 83.64 | 89.59 | 93.06 | 93.75 | 90.01 | 91.9 |
29 | Dominic Rep. | 2014 | 64.15 | 59.56 | 53.7 | 64.97 | 79.14 | 73.31 | 66.45 | 67.2 |
30 | Ecuador | 2006 | 55.97 | 46 | 36.82 | 65.37 | 38.22 | 79.01 | 57.39 | 56.77 |
31 | Egypt | 2013 | 42.96 | 48.68 | 27.64 | 66.78 | 77.77 | 93.01 | 63.1 | 59.62 |
32 | El Salvador | 2007 | 61.06 | 72.79 | 49.35 | 64.68 | 40.8 | 75.4 | 63.79 | 64.02 |
33 | Ethiopia | 2014 | 24.93 | 28.39 | 19.32 | 33.17 | 2.85 | 82.51 | 39.33 | 39.87 |
34 | Fiji | 2014 | 74.43 | 25.7 | 56.98 | 57.2 | 43.56 | 69.68 | 57.56 | 61.3 |
35 | Finland | 2007 | 85.16 | 87.39 | 72.07 | 90.6 | 91.67 | 91.64 | 87.22 | 87.36 |
36 | France | 2007 | 76.99 | 87.19 | 80.56 | 88.36 | 91.79 | 97.96 | 88.23 | 89.36 |
37 | Gabon | 2014 | 75.55 | 42.75 | 52.22 | 63.44 | 2.36 | 72.3 | 55.96 | 59.46 |
38 | Gambia | 2006 | 70.76 | 49.68 | 45.63 | 57.79 | 6.31 | 61.86 | 51.78 | 54.92 |
39 | Germany | 2007 | 81.36 | 84.49 | 76.35 | 87.52 | 92.57 | 92.43 | 86.48 | 87.44 |
40 | Ghana | 2014 | 62.3 | 54.48 | 27.85 | 45.77 | 3.96 | 85.72 | 54.17 | 55.67 |
41 | Greece | 2007 | 68.15 | 83.53 | 76.51 | 83.41 | 85.44 | 92.38 | 82.59 | 83.44 |
42 | Guatemala | 2014 | 48 | 74.96 | 26.23 | 57.23 | 42.95 | 83.01 | 60.42 | 57.71 |
43 | Guinea | 2014 | 57.21 | 31.29 | 21.72 | 41.38 | 2.73 | 76.19 | 44.4 | 46.82 |
44 | Guyana | 2006 | 80.52 | 62.07 | 56.43 | 55.51 | 44.1 | 43.34 | 56.44 | 59.99 |
45 | Haiti | 2010 | 34.21 | 62.93 | 28.71 | 50.84 | 1 | 45.88 | 39.36 | 38.47 |
46 | Honduras | 2014 | 74.61 | 71.19 | 28.45 | 58.46 | 39.51 | 71.84 | 61.42 | 60.57 |
47 | Hungary | 2009 | 92.14 | 85.86 | 65.93 | 89.31 | 89.62 | 91.47 | 86.99 | 87.02 |
48 | Iceland | 2008 | 89.32 | 64.89 | 81.47 | 80.36 | 91.88 | 70.11 | 77.86 | 81.39 |
49 | India | 2014 | 43.78 | 44.93 | 14.1 | 45.12 | 32.98 | 91.23 | 52.38 | 50.87 |
50 | Indonesia | 2014 | 56.25 | 71.79 | 20.4 | 49.92 | 33.89 | 86.83 | 59.65 | 57.96 |
51 | Ireland | 2014 | 99.52 | 89.78 | 89.37 | 91.72 | 91.88 | 90.47 | 92.15 | 95.2 |
52 | Israel | 2010 | 71.59 | 83.51 | 75.06 | 67.25 | 90.37 | 80.29 | 78.15 | 80.79 |
53 | Italy | 2007 | 68.17 | 83.24 | 70.46 | 78.72 | 86.52 | 97.92 | 82.85 | 83.57 |
54 | Ivory Coast | 2007 | 63.35 | 40.17 | 41.85 | 52.15 | 2.85 | 70.72 | 49.83 | 53.08 |
55 | Jamaica | 2007 | 80.64 | 70 | 63.13 | 69.52 | 7.11 | 68.56 | 62.72 | 66.57 |
56 | Japan | 2014 | 50.41 | 76.54 | 43.39 | 75.59 | 87.91 | 88.1 | 72.26 | 68.81 |
57 | Jordan | 2006 | 79.36 | 59.47 | 67.97 | 71.54 | 41.11 | 84.27 | 70.31 | 73.94 |
58 | Kenya | 2007 | 27.19 | 46.79 | 29.61 | 46.02 | 3.72 | 82.92 | 46.46 | 45.8 |
59 | Kuwait | 2008 | 61.31 | 75.01 | 78.96 | 76.28 | 90.41 | 59.54 | 70.76 | 72.18 |
60 | Lebanon | 2006 | 86.92 | 62.3 | 70.38 | 81.04 | 43.26 | 74.55 | 70.5 | 74.2 |
61 | Lesotho | 2014 | 80.48 | 41.22 | 25.58 | 48.74 | 6.87 | 54.09 | 45.94 | 48.77 |
62 | Luxembourg | 2007 | 100 | 88.46 | 96.09 | 97.51 | 48.25 | 80.06 | 85.62 | 89.59 |
63 | Madagascar | 2014 | 62.47 | 36.71 | 11.21 | 48.02 | 2.73 | 65.1 | 42.9 | 42.98 |
64 | Malawi | 2013 | 49.9 | 52.47 | 26.25 | 41.95 | 6.99 | 64.35 | 45.4 | 46.09 |
65 | Malaysia | 2010 | 89.03 | 69.62 | 64.71 | 75.92 | 87.52 | 83.17 | 79.12 | 81.07 |
66 | Mali | 2014 | 50.97 | 41.67 | 22.46 | 44.1 | 1.12 | 75.98 | 46.07 | 46.72 |
67 | Malta | 2009 | 99.76 | 87.06 | 83.18 | 96.04 | 49.74 | 52.58 | 76.16 | 78.24 |
68 | Mauritania | 2014 | 79.3 | 58.16 | 19.77 | 51.82 | 1.37 | 66.99 | 51.45 | 52.55 |
69 | Mauritius | 2014 | 91.12 | 84.89 | 58.78 | 82.06 | 42.61 | 45.32 | 66.61 | 66.81 |
70 | Mexico | 2014 | 63.45 | 68.45 | 44.3 | 68.92 | 40.12 | 71.72 | 62.29 | 61.61 |
71 | Moldova | 2007 | 67.96 | 69.67 | 44.9 | 84.17 | 39.27 | 67.22 | 64.04 | 61.7 |
72 | Mongolia | 2014 | 84.88 | 65.73 | 16.76 | 59.4 | 1.43 | 71.89 | 56.91 | 55.63 |
73 | Montenegro | 2010 | 81.65 | 79.55 | 72.69 | 94.41 | 5.08 | 56.33 | 65.48 | 66.92 |
74 | Morocco | 2014 | 60.71 | 53.68 | 45.87 | 83.86 | 37.71 | 89.5 | 65.95 | 64.33 |
75 | Myanmar | 2014 | 56.93 | 56.33 | 11.89 | 42.07 | 1 | 44.74 | 39.03 | 38.4 |
76 | Nepal | 2013 | 13.26 | 39.95 | 24.97 | 44.85 | 2.79 | 70.69 | 38.18 | 36.7 |
77 | Netherlands | 2014 | 97.64 | 88.48 | 85.98 | 93.26 | 92.75 | 95.41 | 92.84 | 95.24 |
78 | New Zealand | 2008 | 76.62 | 90.04 | 79.32 | 91.46 | 50.44 | 80.05 | 79.17 | 80.12 |
79 | Nicaragua | 2012 | 61.15 | 61.69 | 34.97 | 56.57 | 40.24 | 57.38 | 53.99 | 53.56 |
80 | Niger | 2014 | 54.67 | 50.44 | 32.41 | 35.3 | 1.74 | 74.33 | 47.92 | 50.86 |
81 | Nigeria | 2009 | 65.1 | 47.51 | 12.39 | 52.93 | 3.47 | 89.37 | 54.36 | 52.53 |
82 | Norway | 2013 | 80.32 | 72.93 | 81.74 | 85.52 | 91.68 | 92.27 | 84.48 | 86.83 |
83 | Pakistan | 2007 | 40.85 | 43.25 | 23.4 | 44.12 | 32.38 | 87.55 | 51.83 | 51.16 |
84 | Panama | 2009 | 89.59 | 71.32 | 50.84 | 81.17 | 47.74 | 60.74 | 67.7 | 67.56 |
85 | Paraguay | 2012 | 62.44 | 56.59 | 36.33 | 65.09 | 39.86 | 77.61 | 60.13 | 59.39 |
86 | Peru | 2011 | 69.02 | 82.53 | 32.33 | 58.27 | 36.87 | 84.74 | 66.14 | 65.24 |
87 | Philippines | 2006 | 65.22 | 52.73 | 30.26 | 49.7 | 39.96 | 81.96 | 58.39 | 59.19 |
88 | Poland | 2014 | 77.73 | 76.38 | 57.4 | 92.23 | 89.22 | 88.82 | 81.32 | 79.32 |
89 | Portugal | 2007 | 82.71 | 87.1 | 76.48 | 91.1 | 88.73 | 93.85 | 87.61 | 88.21 |
90 | Romania | 2014 | 60.67 | 83.22 | 48.07 | 82.02 | 82.39 | 89.82 | 76.51 | 73.36 |
91 | Rwanda | 2014 | 34.81 | 63.91 | 17.27 | 39.87 | 7.05 | 71.53 | 45.56 | 43.83 |
92 | Saudi Arabia | 2009 | 62.95 | 76.19 | 69 | 71.18 | 83.25 | 60.43 | 68.43 | 69.75 |
93 | Senegal | 2012 | 57.58 | 47.32 | 29.33 | 58.91 | 3.53 | 87.9 | 54.64 | 54.59 |
94 | Sierra Leone | 2011 | 69.7 | 46.89 | 19.84 | 38.92 | 3.16 | 65.1 | 45.9 | 48.29 |
95 | Singapore | 2009 | 99.01 | 95.35 | 92.18 | 88.25 | 96.12 | 71.77 | 88.27 | 91.52 |
96 | South Africa | 2014 | 72.64 | 65.18 | 41.53 | 61.39 | 41.93 | 88.04 | 66.72 | 67.54 |
97 | South Korea | 2014 | 62.52 | 63.76 | 43.81 | 73.55 | 42.42 | 89.58 | 67.03 | 66.05 |
98 | Spain | 2007 | 78.33 | 81.36 | 74.93 | 87.72 | 90.22 | 95.93 | 85.92 | 86.71 |
99 | Swaziland | 2014 | 77.83 | 43.61 | 59.31 | 60.2 | 6.37 | 36.55 | 47.48 | 51.92 |
100 | Sweden | 2007 | 88.33 | 86.26 | 80.84 | 84.38 | 94.73 | 96.03 | 89.41 | 91.73 |
101 | Switzerland | 2014 | 95.02 | 70.51 | 91.77 | 87.57 | 94.47 | 93.4 | 88.79 | 93.18 |
102 | Syria | 2011 | 53.48 | 55.43 | 51.94 | 65.49 | 1 | 52.73 | 48.93 | 50.02 |
103 | Tanzania | 2007 | 35.61 | 53.2 | 16.78 | 31.93 | 3.04 | 55.74 | 37.71 | 37.42 |
104 | Thailand | 2012 | 83.87 | 59.54 | 42.9 | 72.93 | 80.93 | 81.22 | 72.06 | 71.71 |
105 | Togo | 2014 | 78.62 | 46.54 | 25.04 | 57.99 | 3.72 | 73.38 | 53.7 | 54.25 |
106 | Trinid &Tobago | 2012 | 86.13 | 68.86 | 58.65 | 67.24 | 41.73 | 53.54 | 63.09 | 65.62 |
107 | Tunisia | 2008 | 70.83 | 48.71 | 41.68 | 76.78 | 2.67 | 86.29 | 60.45 | 60.63 |
108 | Turkey | 2014 | 51.09 | 66.13 | 50.76 | 72.49 | 81.59 | 91.88 | 71.33 | 69.88 |
109 | Uganda | 2013 | 44.01 | 58.02 | 21.59 | 37.01 | 4.52 | 70.23 | 45.48 | 45.69 |
110 | United Kingdom | 2006 | 81.91 | 89.75 | 79.57 | 90.54 | 93.3 | 94.9 | 89.06 | 89.91 |
111 | United States | 2007 | 65.17 | 85.34 | 67.13 | 82.45 | 91.9 | 92.1 | 81.8 | 81.15 |
112 | Uruguay | 2008 | 65.66 | 68.87 | 51.35 | 65.92 | 42.1 | 85.45 | 67.23 | 68.14 |
113 | Venezuela | 2006 | 62.32 | 47.83 | 38.48 | 68.43 | 41.65 | 65.68 | 56.17 | 55.45 |
114 | Vietnam | 2014 | 80.26 | 49.28 | 16.43 | 63.78 | 31.92 | 71.13 | 56.69 | 54.98 |
115 | Yemen | 2008 | 53.37 | 63.83 | 23.57 | 41.91 | 1.68 | 62.24 | 46.51 | 46.66 |
116 | Zambia | 2007 | 64.24 | 63.96 | 27.92 | 45.69 | 4.09 | 73.93 | 52.96 | 54.04 |
E1, E2, S1, S2, S3, P and KOF are for the Year-H when the overall index AEMC attained maximum (Gmax) during 2006-2014. AEMC Indices are computed by the author. |
Table A3. Economic, Social and Political Dimensions and Overall Indices of Globalization in Different Countries
Country | Year-L | E1 | E2 | S1 | S2 | S3 | P | KOF | AEMC | |
1 | Albania | 2006 | 35.89 | 58.68 | 52.56 | 69.39 | 2.24 | 67.63 | 51.18 | 50.86 |
2 | Algeria | 2007 | 49.62 | 47.76 | 33.94 | 64.81 | 2.05 | 48.49 | 43.47 | 42.36 |
3 | Argentina | 2012 | 41.13 | 30.68 | 43.54 | 72.69 | 40.54 | 92.83 | 57.89 | 57.09 |
4 | Australia | 2013 | 68.41 | 78.01 | 73.79 | 85.8 | 92.9 | 90.42 | 81.97 | 82.24 |
5 | Austria | 2013 | 85.52 | 76.5 | 86.51 | 91.31 | 95.46 | 96.36 | 89.09 | 91.36 |
6 | Azerbaijan | 2009 | 59.96 | 57.99 | 38.9 | 78.95 | 34.51 | 55.51 | 55.35 | 52.78 |
7 | Belgium | 2013 | 95.51 | 73.19 | 84.04 | 96.99 | 91.01 | 96.51 | 90.7 | 92.32 |
8 | Benin | 2006 | 28.32 | 40.26 | 28.88 | 35.4 | 2.54 | 71.83 | 40.22 | 41.61 |
9 | Bhutan | 2007 | 34.97 | 56.4 | 46.37 | 41.28 | 5.32 | 21.18 | 33.12 | 35.44 |
10 | Bolivia | 2011 | 56.44 | 50.56 | 37.79 | 58.44 | 2.91 | 76.81 | 52.76 | 53.62 |
11 | Botswana | 2012 | 60.07 | 53.5 | 56.45 | 55.16 | 4.95 | 39.77 | 45.21 | 49.05 |
12 | Brazil | 2008 | 48.27 | 53.34 | 20.26 | 68.5 | 38.23 | 92.27 | 59.38 | 55.59 |
13 | Bulgaria | 2010 | 71.76 | 74.41 | 50.21 | 82.83 | 40.81 | 83.13 | 70.59 | 69.36 |
14 | Burkina Faso | 2006 | 16.39 | 50.78 | 32.95 | 36.9 | 3.9 | 71.57 | 40.68 | 41.27 |
15 | Burundi | 2006 | 24.06 | 35.17 | 16.96 | 35.39 | 4.15 | 36.97 | 27.89 | 26.92 |
16 | C. Africa Rep. | 2007 | 40.14 | 22.02 | 15.27 | 32.43 | 2.24 | 57.98 | 32.8 | 34.45 |
17 | Cambodia | 2011 | 70.4 | 50.86 | 26.14 | 44.44 | 2.17 | 59.93 | 46.83 | 49.02 |
18 | Cameroon | 2010 | 35.79 | 41.44 | 16.83 | 51.95 | 2.73 | 70.25 | 42.67 | 40.16 |
19 | Canada | 2013 | 74.03 | 77.68 | 81.23 | 92.24 | 94.97 | 92.94 | 85.6 | 86.39 |
20 | Chad | 2011 | 50.22 | 28.12 | 19.94 | 36.74 | 2.91 | 58.55 | 37.11 | 39.14 |
21 | Chile | 2013 | 77.71 | 75.92 | 38.21 | 76.16 | 40.69 | 88.74 | 71.11 | 69.54 |
22 | China | 2012 | 41.21 | 56.27 | 16.75 | 65.54 | 78.02 | 84.8 | 60.42 | 55.12 |
23 | Colombia | 2008 | 54.98 | 42.87 | 30.73 | 70.8 | 38.22 | 78.48 | 56.48 | 54.44 |
24 | Congo D. Rep. | 2006 | 19.87 | 28.69 | 8.76 | 34.02 | 1 | 44.96 | 26.11 | 24.95 |
25 | Congo Rep. | 2008 | 91.35 | 37.23 | 31.94 | 40.9 | 1.74 | 39.88 | 42.91 | 47.78 |
26 | Costa Rica |